Showing posts with label ECB. Show all posts
Showing posts with label ECB. Show all posts

8/01/2020

Public debt monetisation and the credibility of the ECB




July 28 2020
By Pompeo Della Posta



What stops public debt being monetised to avoid the pain of prolonged austerity after the pandemic? An obsolete economic theory of ‘credibility’.

In the conditions, akin to wartime, resulting from the Covid-19 pandemic, public debt is being created—and more will have to be created—to meet the exceptional fiscal needs arising. Many economists, of different orientations (Blanchard and Pisani-Ferry, Giavazzi and Tabellini, Galì, De Grauwe), suggest that this debt should be ‘monetised’—bought up on primary markets by central banks, with the creation of new money. This would avoid the accumulation of public debt and the consequent need to adopt future austerity policies for its repayment, hindering growth.

The main objections to such direct-money financing of public expenditure in the European economic and monetary union (EMU) relate to its institutional feasibility—given the requirements of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union—and the negative effects it would supposedly have on the anti-inflationary credibility of the European Central Bank.

The first objection is, of course, rather serious—although only so long as insufficient political will prevents its resolution via treaty change, to which I shall return. To deal with the second, it is worth recalling the evolution of the theory of ‘credibility’.

‘Rational expectations’


The first generation of credibility theory, dating back to the 1970s and 1980s—in particular the contributions of Kydland and Prescott and Barro and Gordon—contended that central banks should follow monetary rules rather than exercise discretion. In the latter case, it was asserted, the ‘rational expectations’ of economic actors would anticipate the central bank’s ‘time inconsistency’ problem, namely its purported incentive to renege on the initial promise not to run an expansionary monetary policy and instead reduce unemployment by managing a surprise injection of money to increase the price level—thereby reducing real wages and inducing employers to hire more workers.

The expectation of inflation would, it was contended, pre-emptively become a self-fulfilling prophecy, leaving no real effect on unemployment and production, which would remain anchored to levels presumed naturally dictated by the market. ‘Tying the hands’ of central banks by imposing strict rules on them, then, would solve the ‘time inconsistency’ problem.

This theory—however questionable its deterministic chain of argumentation—was convenient for those believing in the unconditional virtues of free markets and unconcerned about unemployment in the post-Keynesian era. It became the theoretical basis on which the ECB’s institutional architecture was built, to preserve its anti-inflationary credibility.

Optimum currency areas


This conclusion conflicted with the basic approach of the parallel flow of literature on optimum currency areas (OCA). From a different perspective, this also implied tying the hands of the central bank, although through participation in a fixed exchange-rate system or a monetary union, rather than by imposing stringent domestic rules.

More specifically, OCA theory examined the conditions to be met for a currency or monetary union—in which exchange-rate and monetary independence were renounced—to be optimal. It did so by asking how likely an asymmetric shock affecting a country would be (Kenen’s product-diversification criterion), how easily it could be absorbed by automatic market mechanisms (Mundell‘s criterion on mobility and flexibility of labour and capital) and how effective the forsworn exchange-rate instrument might have been (McKinnon‘s criterion on the degree of openness).

Credibility theory, being based until then on deterministic models, should not have been part of this debate, but it was wrongly credited as being the ‘new’ OCA theory (Tavlas). In this view, since monetary independence produced only an inflationary bias, without any substantive benefit, giving it up by joining a currency or monetary union would always be optimal, because it would avoid running the risk of inflation.

Justice was only done when the second generation of credibility theory took instead a stochastic approach—recognising contingency and randomness. This led to the same conclusion as OCA theory: if production is hit by an unexpected and asymmetric shock, one can no longer conclude that rules (whether a domestic or an external tying of hands) are always preferable to discretion.

If the problem is uncertainty as to central-bank behaviour over time, credibility is at issue, but this is not the problem when a stochastic shock affects the economy and needs to be absorbed in the here and now (Lohmann). The rules, therefore, should not be fixed, but rather state-contingent (Svensson) and policy-makers cannot gain credibility by following policies that are not credible (Drazen and Masson). How, in 1992, for example, could the Italian central bank gain credibility and an anti-inflationary reputation by following a fixed rule of exchange-rate stability that damaged the Italian economy?

Less costly


And, in the current situation, how could the ECB lose its anti-inflationary credibility if it agreed to buy government bonds on the primary market or if it financed citizens directly by crediting their current account—which would not entail any inflationary risk and would be less costly for the euro-area economies than recourse to debt? After all, that is what the Bank of England and the Federal Reserve are doing. In fact, the future repayment of these debts would risk jeopardising the economic-recovery capacities of the countries in question, which would have to resort to recessionary austerity policies.

During the eurozone crisis, European countries already followed restrictive fiscal policies, the opposite of what the United Kingdom and the United States did. It is not to these policies—which perversely increased the ratio of public debt to gross domestic product, due to their larger contractionary effect on the denominator—that we owe the end of the crisis. Rather, that came with the reassurance of the ‘whatever it takes’ monetary commitment by the then ECB president, Mario Draghi.

Restrictive fiscal policies were implemented not because they were coherent or validated but because of the distrust of European countries towards one another. It was this mistrust which fostered the belief that, without limiting fiscal looseness, the associated ‘moral hazard’ would produce excessive growth of public debt.

It seems that today we shall make a similar mistake—this time in terms of an inappropriate monetary, rather than fiscal, policy. The reason, however, is the same—mutual mistrust and the fear that the expectation of debt monetisation would induce irresponsible, ‘freeriding’ behaviour.

Such fear is engendered by the continuing incompleteness and indeed fragmentation of economic and monetary union. Which carries a high cost—a cost that should be sufficient to foster the political will necessary to avoid it and so to enjoy the full benefits of EMU.


5/05/2020

EU Court Faces ‘Declaration of War’ From German Top Judges


Source: MSN
May 5 2020
By Bloomberg

The European Union’s top court faced the most stinging attack in its 68-year history -- not from Brexiteers, but from its German counterpart.

In a long-awaited ruling on the European Central Bank’s quantitative easing program, Germany’s constitutional court in Karlsruhe accused the EU Court of Justice of overstepping its powers when it backed the ECB’s controversial policy.

The German court said the EU judges’ December 2018 ruling that QE was in line with EU rules was “objectively arbitrary” and is “methodologically no longer justifiable.” It gave the ECB a three-month ultimatum to fix flaws in the measure.

“This is a declaration of war on the ECJ, and it will have consequences,” said Joachim Wieland, a law professor at the University of Administrative Sciences, who sees the real challenge in the future relationship between the EU court and national constitutional tribunals. “It’s an invitation for other countries to simply ignore decisions that they don’t like.”

German Judges Give ECB Three Months to Fix Flaws in QE Program

The ruling is a direct challenge to the supremacy of the EU judges, whose rulings are binding across the 27-nation bloc. The German court said this no longer applies in extreme examples when the EU tribunal fails in its duties.

The bigger issue is that the ruling has opened a Pandora’s box on the EU legal order, said Guntram Wolff, director of the Brussels-based Bruegel think tank.

Calling an ECJ judgment “ultra vires,” or going beyond one’s legal powers, “is a huge issue for the integrity of EU law,” Wolff said in an email. “Every national court can now challenge the EU court by saying what the German court is doing, is also applicable to us.”

It’s not only the toughest criticism the Luxembourg-based EU judges have faced by one of the bloc’s most senior courts, it also creates a risk that other nations will start to doubt their authority.

The EU court has long been contentious among the ranks of Brexiteers, who won the U.K.’s 2016 referendum campaign. In recent months it’s also traded blows with Poland’s nationalist government over reforms to the country’s legal system.

Poland’s Deputy Justice Minister Sebastian Kaleta said the ruling showed “yet again” that the EU doesn’t have the authority to meddle in or question Polish judicial changes.

Laurent Pech, a professor of European law at Middlesex University in London, said the ruling could lead to clashes with “autocratic authorities in Hungary and Poland.”

These countries “are no doubt going to use this ruling as a pretext to further undermine the fundamental principles underlying the EU’s legal system,” Pech said. They will instruct “their courts to disobey inconvenient ECJ rulings whenever convenient for the ruling party.”

The ECB’s asset-purchase program has been a concern for the German court since its inception. In 2017, its judges asked the EU court for an interim decision aimed at limiting the ECB’s leeway, but the EU tribunal rejected the restrictive reading of the law suggested by their German counterparts.

Aside from the battle of the judges, the German ruling has implications for a wide swathe of other EU institutions.

For some, a prime risk of the ruling is to the independence of the ECB. If the German court determines where the blurry line between monetary and fiscal policy lies, then that means the nation is essentially imposing its own national orthodoxy on a European-level institution.

“We have always been critical of the way in which the ECB has tended to blur the lines between momentary policy, which is its original task, and fiscal and economic policies,” said Ralph Brinkhaus, the parliamentary leader of Chancellor Angela Merkel’s Christian Democrat bloc. “We will now use the ruling of the Constitutional Court as an occasion to question its decisions once again, in a constructive and critical dialog.”

The EU tribunal doesn’t comment on rulings from national courts, Juan-Carlos Gonzalez, head of the court’s press service, said by phone.

While the European Commission said it would need to study the ruling in detail first, a spokesman pointed to how the EU’s top court rulings are meant to be the final word in legal conflicts.

“We reaffirm the primacy of EU law and the fact that rulings by the EU Court of Justice are binding on all national courts,” Eric Mamer, spokesman of the European Commission said at a regular press briefing on Tuesday.


5/04/2020

Is the ECB stimulus program legal? A German court is about to decide


Source: CNBC
May 4 2020
By Silvia Amaro


  • Analysts don’t expect the court to rule the program illegal, but the decision could impose restrictions on what the ECB does.
  • The ECB unveiled in March the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme — which will buy 750 billion euros ($819 billion) in euro zone government bonds this year. 
  • This coronavirus program has fewer strings attached than previous stimulus— and could therefore be even more vulnerable to court rulings.
European debt holders are cautiously awaiting a ruling from a German court, which could impact how the European Central Bank (ECB) faces the ongoing economic crisis.

Germany’s constitutional court in the city of Karlsruhe will announce on Tuesday whether the ECB’s public sector purchase program — which buys government debt in the euro zone and was initially introduced in 2015 — is legal under German law.

Analysts don’t expect the court to rule the program illegal, but the decision could impose restrictions on what the ECB does.

“We need to watch the risk that the court could spell out conditions for the ECB’s sovereign bond purchases that could make it more difficult for the bank to use this part of its monetary toolkit flexibly and efficiently,” Holger Schmieding, chief economist at Berenberg, said in a note last week.
What’s at stake?

The decision, back in 2015, to purchase government bonds, to keep borrowing costs relatively low across the euro area, came with certain conditions. Only countries with an investment-grade rating could feature in the program and the bond purchases were linked to the size of the 19 economies —just to name two of the restrictions.

The initiative, also known as quantitative easing or QE, ended in 2018 and was restarted in November, 2019.

The First Senate of the Federal Constitutional Court in Karlsruhe, southwestern Germany on November 5, 2019.
However, the coronavirus pandemic has pushed the ECB to take a step further. It announced in March the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme (PEPP) — which will buy 750 billion euros ($819 billion) in euro zone government bonds this year. This latest package is in addition to the 20 billion euros that the ECB was already buying every month since November.

The difference, though, is that PEPP has fewer strings attached — and could therefore be even more vulnerable to court rulings.

For example, Greek debt, which doesn’t have an investment-grade rating and is ineligible under QE, can be bought under the coronavirus package. This means that if the German court imposes restrictions on quantitative easing in the first place then these might also have to apply to the coronavirus package.

Berenberg’s Schmieding said “we cannot rule out the possibility” that the German court tries to impose significant limits on ECB purchases in its ruling on the Public Sector Purchase Program (PSPP), referring to the program introduced in 2015 to buy government bonds.

“If so, we would likely get a new court case against the PEPP immediately — which could then take time to wind its way through the German and European courts,” Schmieding added.

Furthermore, the coronavirus package or PEPP respects the size of the 19 economies, but it has been designed in a way that the ECB could buy more Italian or Spanish debt, than say Dutch debt, to keep costs lower for troubled economies. This is something that judges could also have issues with.

“The question of the legality of PEPP — with less PSPP-style limits… is already looming on the horizon,” Carsten Nickel, deputy director of research at Teneo, said in note last week.

5/01/2020

EU unity disintegrates: Huge state aid row erupts between member states as Germany benefit


Source: EXPRESS
May 1 2020
By Joe Barnes

GERMANY has benefited from more than half the emergency state aid approved by the European Commission during the coronavirus pandemic.

Berlin, the European Union’s largest economy, has accounted for 52 percent of the total value of emergency coronavirus state aid handouts cleared by the bloc’s Brussels-based executive. The Commission relaxed its normally-strict state aid restrictions in March to allow EU27 governments to pump money into their ailing economies and companies damaged by the introduction of coronavirus lockdowns. Eurocrats have sanctioned more than £1.6 trillion worth of national schemes so far.

France and Italy share joint second place, each with 17 percent of the total allowed by the Commission.

Brussels has signaled it will allow governments to continue to make similar investments until at least the end of the year.

But some European capitals have complained about the amounts the cash-rich German government has been able to pump into its economy.

They fear the vast sums have handed Berlin an unfair advantage in the bloc’s single market, and the Commission’s relaxed attitude could even cause permanent distortions.

“There is clearly a risk of a breakdown of the internal market in Europe,” a senior Spanish government official told Reuters.

“Not all the countries of the internal market have access to this liquidity.

“Germany has deep pockets and can afford it.”

Berlin has issued government-backed loans to sports giant Adidas, holiday operator TUI and is in talks with national airline Lufthansa over a £7.8 billion rescue package.

Carlo Amati, of the Italian flight attendants union ANPAV, warned: “The state aid that some European countries are discussing with airlines risks distorting competition and creating benefits for some when the sector restarts.”

Ryanair’s chief executive Michael O’Leary has said he is preparing to challenge more than £26 billion handed to rival airlines in the European courts.

Commission executive vice-president Margrethe Vestager, the bloc’s competition boss, has insisted the suspension of state aid rules was “fully legitimate” to save jobs and businesses.

“There are differences in how much member states can spend depending on this fiscal space,” she said.

“But we preserve the single market because we really need the single market for our recovery.”

But EU officials have cast doubt on the Commission’s ability to protect the single market for significant distortions.

One source said: “If you look at the scale of what Germany in particular, but also some others, are doing – any notion of level playing field or single market integrity has gone out of the window.”

Spain has called for EU leaders to consider the inequality generated by allowing cash-rich governments to pour cash into their economies.

While “increased flexibility for national responses is needed and welcome, it is vital to avoid this leading to a more unequal EU”, Madrid said in a note.

To restore the level playing field, the capital wants the bloc’s poorer countries to be compensated through the next seven-year budget.

Ana Botin, the head of Spanish bank Santander, said: “Europe needs more fiscal firepower and we need it now.”


4/30/2020

ECB says it’s ready to increase coronavirus stimulus as euro zone posts worst GDP since records began

GS - Christine Lagarde - 106511575

Source: CNBC
April 30 2020


  • The central bank decided Thursday to keep its interest rates unchanged, but it eased conditions for banks.
  • The decision came on the same day that data revealed the 19-member region’s economy contracted by 3.8% in the first quarter — the lowest reading since records began in 1995.
  • Data released earlier this month showed that if the central bank keeps buying governments bonds at the current daily pace, the coronavirus stimulus program will reach its limit in October.

    The European Central Bank (ECB) said Thursday that it had kept interest rates unchanged but was ready to increase its coronavirus stimulus program if needed, as the euro zone faces a deep economic crisis.

    The central bank also announced that it had eased lending conditions for banks.

    The decision came on the same day that data revealed the 19-member region’s economy contracted by 3.8% in the first quarter — the lowest reading since records began in 1995 — as the coronavirus pandemic hit business activity in the region hard.

    “The euro area is facing an economic contraction of a magnitude and speed that are unprecedented in peacetime,” ECB President Christine Lagarde said at a press conference Thursday. She added that the central bank expects a GDP contraction between 5% and 12% this year.

    The ECB is deploying a massive stimulus package to mitigate some of the economic shock. In March, it announced a 750-billion-euro ($813 billion) package known as the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme (PEPP) which saw it start additional purchases of governments bonds. Data released earlier this month showed that if the central bank keeps buying governments bonds at the current daily pace, the program will reach its limit in October.

    “These purchases will continue to be conducted in a flexible manner over time, across asset classes and among jurisdictions,” Lagarde said.

    In a statement outlining the recent decisions, the ECB said that “the Governing Council is fully prepared to increase the size of the PEPP and adjust its composition, by as much as necessary and for as long as needed.”

    The ECB also last month reduced costs for commercial banks to support lending activity and on Thursday said it would reduce these interest rates further.

    “The Governing Council decided to reduce the interest rate on TLTRO III operations during the period from June 2020 to June 2021 to 50 basis points below the average interest rate on the Eurosystem’s main refinancing operations prevailing over the same period,” the ECB said.

    TLTRO (targeted longer-term refinancing operations) are loans that the ECB provides at cheap rates to banks in the euro area. The aim is to encourage banks to lend to customers in an effort to stimulate the real economy.

    Nonetheless, borrowing costs for periphery countries, such as Italy, have risen in recent weeks as market participants worry about debt sustainability in the long-term.

    Italy ended 2019 with a public debt pile above 130% of debt-to-GDP (gross domestic product) and this is expected to grow as Rome deals with a vast health and economic crisis.

    Fitch Ratings downgraded Italy’s credit rating to one notch above junk level on Tuesday. The ratings agency also warned “downward pressure on the rating could resume if the government does not implement a credible economic growth and fiscal strategy that enhances confidence that general government debt/GDP will be placed on a downward path over time.”

4/23/2020

This Eurozone Crisis Will Be Even Worse Than Last Time


Source: Jacobin
April 23 2020
By Etienne Shneider and Felix Syrovatka

European Commission president Ursula von der Leyen has apologized to Italy for the EU’s underwhelming response to coronavirus. But faced with economic meltdown, battle lines are hardening between the German-led bloc and the states of the Southern periphery — and the splits are about to become even more irreconcilable.

The coronavirus crisis is often compared to a natural disaster, or, as European Commission president Ursula von der Leyen called it, an “external shock” befalling our society from the outside. But pandemics don’t come from nowhere. They develop under social conditions and are associated with specific forms of metabolism between humans and nature. Indeed, this was true even of the first emergence of the current pandemic. Capitalist expansion and land grabbing have promoted the emergence of zoonoses, i.e., infectious diseases that, like SARS-CoV-2, are transmitted between animals and humans. The clearing of forests for industrial agriculture tears down natural barriers, as wild animals with previously unknown viruses are driven out of their habitats and come into contact with livestock and humans.

The comparison of the coronavirus with a natural disaster is even more misleading considering how it has spread globally. This is most obvious in the sense that China’s ever closer integration into the capitalist world market in recent decades facilitated the international transmission of the virus. But COVID-19 rapidly spread to — and through — Europe because austerity policy has severely damaged the health care systems in many countries, particularly in the aftermath of the Eurozone crisis, and because effective measures to contain the virus were taken far too late.

At the beginning of March — even as the EU backed Greece in suspending the Geneva Convention on Refugees in that country’s attempt to seal off its external borders — the European Commission vehemently opposed border closures within the Schengen area (covering most of the continental EU) such as could have contained COVID-19. Apparently, safeguarding the four freedoms (free movement of persons, goods, services, and capital) — the symbolic cornerstones of the neoliberal European single-market project — was seen as more important than a robust containment of the looming pandemic by reducing cross-border travel.

Moreover, complicating the “natural disaster” analogy, the economic disasters resulting from this crisis can hardly be attributed solely to the virus and the measures to contain it. Rather, the pandemic — like the bursting of the subprime mortgage bubble on the US real estate and financial markets in 2007 — reveals existing vulnerabilities and crisis tendencies. The pandemic was rather more like the needle that burst the speculative bubbles on the stock markets at the beginning of March.

These bubbles had been building up against the background of an already weak productive capital accumulation, fueled by the global oversupply of liquidity, especially as a result of the historically unprecedented long-term interest rate cuts and the quantitative easing programs of the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank (ECB). The US stock market in particular has been considered highly overvalued for years. Simultaneously, capital accumulation in industrial production was weak due to accumulated overcapacities, especially in the automotive sector, but also in the chemical and steel industries. In Germany, for instance, industry had been confronted with a decline in value added and a crisis in the exploitation of capital since 2018. Hence, the economic cycle that began after the global financial crisis in 2008 had already come to an end in 2019, at the latest.

Yet the corona crisis is fundamentally different from the post-2007 global financial and economic crisis. While the latter was triggered by the bursting of the subprime mortgage bubble in the United States and spread from the financial markets to the so-called real economy, the measures to contain the coronavirus in most European countries are bringing a large number of industries, in particular tourism, catering, aviation, and non-food trading, to an almost complete standstill.

This is compounded by a severe decline of production in many industrial sectors, especially as global production networks disintegrate. The collapse of these sectors sucks the rest of the economy into the maelstrom of crisis. Ensuing credit defaults and the price erosion on the bond and stock markets shake up the already fragile banking and financial system in Europe. The default of leveraged loans and collateralized loan obligations, i.e., securitized loans to highly indebted companies, will aggravate this shock.

Despite these differences, this crisis — just like the global financial and economic crisis after 2007 — is likely to be further exacerbated by the architecture of the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). This time, however, the impeding “Eurozone crisis 2.0” could be much deeper, harder, and more life-threatening to the EMU than the last crisis. There are at least three indications of this.

First, the Eurozone crisis from 2008 to 2012 has never been fully overcome, despite official claims to the contrary. Moreover, the fundamental contradictions or “construction errors” of the EMU have not been eliminated, despite eight years of discussions over how to reform the EMU to make it more stable. Finally, this is even more of a problem in that the focal point of this crisis is not a relatively small, peripheral country like Greece, but Italy — the nation that has in recent years become a condensation of the EMU’s wider contradictions.

The Smoldering Eurozone Crisis

Contrary to the European institutions’ official announcements, the last Eurozone crisis was never completely overcome. Although current account imbalances declined as a result of austerity policy, economic development remained weak after the devastating crisis years, especially in the southern European member states.

Greece’s GDP last year was only at 2002 levels, while Spain, Portugal, Italy, and even France have not yet been able to reach their pre-crisis economic levels. Accordingly, unemployment remained high, especially among young people. Average real wages stagnated or fell, as in Spain or Italy, social inequality increased, and public debt surged. Greece alone is burdened by a colossal debt of 180 percent of GDP, despite the debt restructuring in 2012.

The Eurozone crisis thus continued to seethe underneath the surface — but was concealed by ECB policies. Since then-ECB president Mario Draghi’s famous promise to “do whatever it takes” to save the euro in 2012, the ECB has been successful in bringing down the risk premiums for Southern European government bonds with its giant bond purchase program, thus ending the acute phase of the Eurozone crisis.

This did not, however, address the underlying crisis tendencies, but only suppressed them temporarily. Risk premiums for government bonds of Southern European countries have continued to go up and down over the past years, and with the outbreak of the SARS-CoV-2 virus in Europe, they shot up again, bringing Southern European countries under massive pressure on the financial markets once again.

Blocked Eurozone Reform

The corona crisis therefore lays bare the EU’s historic failure. The European elites let the past ten years pass without correcting the fundamental contradictions and constructional flaws of the EMU. Broadly speaking, these arise from two particular features of EMU architecture. First, the ECB’s supranational monetary policy is not matched by effective balancing and risk-sharing mechanisms, i.e., instruments that counteract the development of imbalances between countries and regions in the Eurozone.

Second, because of the so-called monetary financing prohibition, the ECB, unlike other central banks, may not act directly as lender of last resort vis-à-vis the euro countries, i.e., as a central bank with the unlimited capacity to buy up government bonds in the event of a crisis. As a result, Eurozone member states can become insolvent in principle, making them vulnerable to speculative attacks on the financial markets and debt crises.

These flaws and contradictions in the EMU architecture became apparent in the financial and economic crisis after 2007, and potential remedies have been intensively discussed by both the European institutions and European heads of state and government. Since 2012, these discussions revolved around the introduction and expansion of mechanisms for risk-sharing and convergence between the member states, including in particular the demand for common government bonds issued by the euro countries (so-called Eurobonds), the creation of the post of a European finance minister together with an extensive Eurozone budget to promote convergence and to compensate for “asymmetric shocks,” and the demand for a common European deposit guarantee in the Eurozone.

To be sure, these proposals — raised mainly by France and Southern European governments, but also supported by trade unions in Germany — would not challenge the fundamentally crisis-ridden character of capitalist accumulation as such. What they could achieve, though, is to ensure that the contradictions of the EMU will not once again become the catalyst of a deeper crisis in Europe. Nonetheless, these proposals have encountered fierce resistance by the Northern bloc in the Eurozone centered around Germany, also including the Netherlands, Austria, and Finland.

This regional split in the EMU reform discussion is conventionally explained by highlighting the rich countries’ reluctance to establish a “transfer union,” i.e., redistribution from the rich North to the poorer South of the Eurozone. But this is only part of the picture, particularly as France is one of the main net contributors to the EU. While Germany but also other Northern and Eastern European countries integrated into the “central European manufacturing core” have redirected their traditionally strong export orientation toward the emerging markets since the onset of the Eurozone crisis, France has remained closely linked to the Southern member states. This has made the French power bloc highly dependent on the economic development there, and interested in stimulating it as much as possible.

By contrast, although the German power bloc relies on the euro as a key element in its world-market-oriented export strategy and thus on the preservation of the EMU, it seeks to keep the costs for its stabilization and defense to a minimum — and to outsource them, as far as possible, to the European periphery. For this reason, Germany, advocating a “stability union” instead of a fiscal or transfer union, insisted on imposing austerity policy on southern Europe, which not only caused massive damage to social infrastructure such as health-care systems but has also considerably weakened economic development in recent years.

This situation is aggravated by the fact that the financial markets remained largely unregulated, even after the last financial crisis. To make things even worse, the securitization of loans, which played a major role in the last crisis, was revived by the Commission within the framework of the capital markets union, and new financial market risks were created with the introduction of so-called STS securitizations. A European financial transaction tax is also missing until today.

At the same time, the European Banking Union remained unfinished due to German resistance. Thus, mechanisms such as a European deposit guarantee scheme, a regulation of the shadow banking system, as well as a common “backstop” for bank resolution are still lacking, i.e., precisely those mechanisms that would be of central importance now, as there are still non-performing loans in the amount of €786 billion in the balance sheets of European banks (ECB 2020). The corona crisis thus not only hits a fragile monetary union, but also a still unstable and insufficiently regulated European financial system.

Italy, the Epicenter of the Eurozone Crisis 2.0

As if this was not enough, the spread of the coronavirus has so far been particularly dramatic in Italy — the country that has become the point of condensation of the contradictions of the EMU for several years now. Already before the last Eurozone crisis, Italian industry came under massive pressure in the EMU as, lacking a currency of its own, it could no longer maintain its price competitiveness through devaluation. This is particularly the case as important parts of Italy’s manufacturing sector are specialized on consumer goods production such as clothing, shoes, leather goods, and furniture, which is especially sensitive to price competition from peripheral, newly industrializing countries.

As a result, manufacturing dropped from 19.9 percent of GDP in 1999, the year the euro was introduced, to just 15.2 percent ten years later, and almost 1 million jobs were lost in the manufacturing sector between 2001 and 2011 (from 4.8 million down to almost 3.9 million). Industrial decline was further intensified by the crisis and resulted in the enduring economic stagnation of the past decade, turning Italy from an above-average industrialized power to a below-average one, and reducing per capita GDP (PPP) from €1,000 above the Eurozone average to €4,000 below it in 2019.

GDP is currently at 2006 levels, and in the fourth quarter of 2019, the Italian economy even shrank by 0.3 percent — indeed, Italy would have slid into recession even without the coronavirus pandemic. These economic crisis tendencies have been increasingly amalgamated with political crisis tendencies, particularly the erosion of the traditional party system and the rise of the Lega and the Five Star Movement.

At the same time, Italy’s public debt — having surpassed the 100 percent of GDP threshold already in the early 1990s as a result of the crisis of the European Monetary System (EMS) — soared to over 150 percent of GDP during the Eurozone crisis, making it one of the highest in the Eurozone, second only to Greece. The banking and financial system is enormously fragile.

At the beginning of the corona crisis, Italian banks had almost €350 billion of non-performing toxic loans in their balance sheets, which corresponds to about 7 percent of total liabilities. Business bankruptcies as a result of quarantine measures could therefore trigger a cascade of bank insolvencies. Considering the small size of the European bank resolution fund, it is most likely the Italian state that will step in to bail out banks, especially as there is still no backstop to the European resolution fund. This could once again result in a devastating doom loop between banking crisis and public debt crisis, similar to the last Eurozone crisis. This time, however, it could engulf Italy, the third largest economy in the Eurozone, and with it the monetary union as a whole into the abyss.

Contradictions of Crisis Management 

As early as mid-March, then, the ECB was forced to stand up to the rapid rise in risk premiums on Italian government bonds with an unprecedented bond purchase program, the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Program (PEPP), worth €750 billion, in an attempt to renew Draghi’s promise of “whatever it takes.” Already, this intervention, however, led to fierce conflicts between Northern and Southern member states within the ECB’s Governing Council.

Due to the massive volume of the PEPP, the ECB could soon hold more than a third of the total government bonds of some countries, which would give it a politically delicate blocking minority on the issue of possible debt restructuring. In view of the dramatic development of the crisis, it is also unclear how long the ECB will succeed in pushing down risk premiums on Italian and other Southern European government bonds with its bond programs. After risk premiums on Italian bonds declined by the end of March, they have continued to climb again in April.

This has put pressure on the EU finance ministers to agree on measures to stabilize the EMU in face of an impending second Eurozone crisis, bringing fierce confrontations between the Northern and the Southern bloc to a head. First, Italy, Spain, and France are calling for euro bonds, whether limited in time (corona bonds) or not (euro bonds), to reduce borrowing costs and increase debt sustainability in the South, while Germany, the Netherlands, Austria, and Finland continue to reject them.

Second, the Northern and Southern bloc clashed over the question of whether credit from the European rescue scheme active in the last Eurozone crisis, the ESM, should come with the same conditionalities (and stigma) attached to it as in the past. This would imply obligations to implement neoliberal structural reforms such as reducing pensions and social benefits as well as “flexibilizing” the labor market by weakening labor rights and unions in exchange for rescue loans.

Along these lines, the Northern bloc insists that rescue loans should exclusively support additional spending to tackle the corona crisis and not to alleviate existing debt. The Dutch finance minister, Wopke Hoekstra, even went as far as to suggest that the countries worst hit by the pandemic deserved little solidarity as they had failed to build up the financial position to combat the crisis over the past years — effectively raising the middle finger to Italy and Spain.

Ultimately, then, the Northern bloc effectively killed the coronabond initiative during the standoff at the Eurogroup summit of April 7–9 — at least for now. Instead, the Eurogroup agreed on ESM credit lines in the volume of €240 billion, a €25 billion European Investment Bank (EIB) lending facility (credit guarantees), and a €100 billion temporary credit program to support national unemployment systems by the European Commission (SURE). The conditionality for ESM credits is supposed to be weak, but “standardized terms” will be agreed upon by the ESM governing bodies, which suggests that the conflict over conditionality is merely relegated into the ESM. Besides these tangible agreements, a “Recovery Fund” based on “innovative financial instruments” (read, coronabonds) is mentioned, but the momentum for such mutual debt instruments might already be fading.

At least so far, then, the German power bloc was successful in keeping alive and even strengthening the ESM — the central enforcement vehicle of austerity policy and the main political project of the German finance ministry in the EMU reform debate — and at maintaining conditionality for ESM credits, at least in principle. What is also certain, however, is that this agreement is anything but sufficient to avert an impending Italian state bankruptcy and a second Eurozone crisis.

After the April 7–9 summit, Italian prime minister Giuseppe Conte has rejected ESM credits in an attempt to secure his political survival from the resurgence of Matteo Salvini’s Lega. Even if his government accepted them, the current capacity of the ESM will probably not be enough, considering the sheer scale of the crisis. At the same time, tensions within the German power bloc are also increasing, with the main employer-financed economic think tank, the Institute of Economic Research, and even some prominent members of the conservative CDU, now supporting at least temporary coronabonds to prevent a further disruption of the EMU.

Dangers and Opportunities

We are therefore facing a highly contingent historical situation, making it difficult for the Left in Europe to prepare for future battles to be fought. It is not unthinkable that the Eurozone is heading for its breakup, resulting in far-reaching processes of economic renationalization. An Italian bank crisis could push risk premiums up again, leading to speculative attacks against Italy on the financial markets. In a second step, these attacks might also turn against Spain, Portugal, and Greece, particularly as tourism — one of, if not the most, important economic sectors in these countries — will lie idle much longer than other parts of the economy in Europe.

At some point, the ECB could fail to further suppress the speculative dynamics as tensions in the ECB Governing Council escalate over the unlimited expansion of bond purchases. Eventually, this dynamic will lead Italy into insolvency, causing the Eurozone to break up or at least to shrink to a core or “trunk” Eurozone composed of the Northern European bloc, possibly including France. This is possible but unlikely, given the enormous importance of the euro for world-market-oriented capital in Germany and for the geopolitical role of the EU as a whole.

Much more likely in our view is makeshift stabilization of the Eurozone now, and a full-blown neoliberal backlash afterward. The heads of state and government agree to ramp up extensive credit lines within the ESM and emergency loans from the European Investment Bank (EIB), and possibly even introduce some form of coronabonds limited in time and scope, issued via the ESM. However, unlike the initial credit tranches agreed on in mid-April, we expect these support mechanisms to be increasingly tied to strict conditionality, i.e., the implementation of structural reforms.

The Northern bloc led by Germany might even push through a shift of budgetary surveillance competences from the European Commission to the ESM in return for ESM-based coronabonds — a step that has been considered by the German Ministry of Finance due to the “politicized” budgetary surveillance procedures of the European Commission for some time now. Nonetheless, the management of the Eurozone crisis 2.0 results in fierce conflicts in the German power bloc and a renewed strengthening of the far-right Alternative für Deutschland as the extension of the ESM and common European bonds have been red lines for conservatives in Germany in the past.

This is why Germany, in order to bridge these cracks in the power bloc, together with other Northern European countries, is likely to insist that the European fiscal rules are not only reinstated as soon as possible after their current suspension, but also enforced even more rigorously through the new powers of the ESM. The sharp rise in national debt throughout Europe will justify drastic austerity policy cuts with once again devastating social consequences. The modest achievements in the area of climate politics over the past few years (phasing out coal, fleet emission targets) are being protracted and undermined under the pretext that the economy must be restarted at all costs and as quickly as possible.

But the looming Eurozone crisis might also turn into an opportunity for a post-neoliberal policy of social infrastructures and socio-ecological transformation of the Left. The corona crisis has already ingrained into collective consciousness just how important public health care and other critical, foundational social infrastructures are. This is a tremendously strong experience and a solid basis to build broad social alliances against austerity cuts and for a foundational economic renewal. The strategy against a new onslaught of austerity could be impressively simply: individual countries, supported by progressive alliances in the other member states, deliberately ignore the European fiscal rules, performing “strategic disobedience” even after they have been reinstated, thus gradually undermining and ultimately abandoning them.

To be sure, public budgets would then be consolidated through increasing public revenues, for example by introducing or expanding property taxes, securing and successively expanding the fiscal space for a renewal of foundational social infrastructures. At the same time, corporate aid schemes and nationalizations already underway right now should not only be linked to climate protection requirements to rebuild and transform production structures in a socio-ecological way, but also leveled to democratize the economy through public participation. Even the reliance on the world market, especially in such critical areas as the supply of medical goods, is no longer beyond dispute, bringing a balanced, need-oriented re-regionalization of production in Europe back into the realm of the imaginable.


ABOUT THE AUTHOR

Etienne Schneider is a doctoral student at the University of Vienna, exploring the conflicts in the German power bloc over the future development of European economic integration. He is an editor of the German journal PROKLA.

Felix Syrovatka is a doctoral student at the University of Tübingen researching European labor market policy in the crisis. He is an editor of the German journal PROKLA.


3/27/2020

EU Leaders Struggle to Find Way Forward With Economy Tanking


Source: Bloomberg
March 27 2020
By Viktoria Dendrinou and Nikos Chrysoloras

European leaders struggled to agree on a concrete strategy to contain the fallout from the deadly coronavirus, leaving key details to be hammered out in the weeks ahead.

With thousands of people falling ill and hundreds dying every day from the pandemic, the leaders spent much of Thursday arguing over whether a joint communique would hint at financial burden sharing as a way to repair the damage to their economies. Earlier this week, finance ministers had passed the buck to the leaders but the leaders passed it right back. They tasked the finance chiefs with coming up with proposals within two weeks.

A video call was expected to give the green light for the creation of credit lines from the region’s bailout fund to keep borrowing costs low while governments ramp up spending to cushion the impact of the pandemic. But efforts to agree on the exact wording of the common statement ended with a fudge after six hours of talks, as a group of member states including France, Italy and Spain pushed for more radical steps to tackle the economic impact, such as the prospect of joint debt issuance via so-called coronabonds.

That call was backed by European Central Bank President Christine Lagarde who warned leaders they were facing a crisis of “epic” proportions. But her appeals fell largely on deaf ears with Germany and the Netherlands, echoing similar divisions during the sovereign debt crisis that almost tore the bloc apart almost decade ago. The European Stability Mechanism was seen by many countries as a more straightforward solution to the problem of funding the response but Italy pushed back.

While German Chancellor Angela Merkel agreed with the bleak assessment of the situation, she resisted calls for mutualizing debt, warning against unrealistic expectations, according to the officials. Merkel’s tone was more categorical than before, one of the officials said, after nine EU leaders, including France’s Emmanuel Macron, backed the idea of coronabonds in a letter ahead of the meeting. Dutch Prime Minister Mark Rutte backed the German chancellor’s stance on the joint instruments, the officials said.

Merkel’s intervention, delivered via an interpreter with just her photo on screen, came amid dramatic pleas for more action from her counterparts. In an address officials described as emotional, Italian Prime Minister Giuseppe Conte said his whole country was suffering, while Macron warned that the political reaction after this crisis could kill the European project, two of the officials said. Spanish Prime Minister Pedro Sanchez joined Conte in pushing for bolder and faster fiscal action and fought to stop the baton passing back to finance ministers.

Over a heated exchange, countries most hit by the coronavirus were pitted against those from Europe’s fiscally hawkish north. In lieu of concrete decisions and in an effort to bridge the different positions, the leaders asked the presidents of the European Union institutions to come up a with a proposal for an exit strategy, on top of the work assigned to finance minister over the next two weeks.

While some officials interpreted the vagueness in the statement as a win for countries who pushed for steps that went beyond the mobilization of the ESM, there was little evidence that opponents to coronabonds were ready to give ground.

Speaking after the leaders’ call, Merkel said “Germany and others” were not in agreement on joint debt. “For me, the ESM is the preferred instrument -- it was created for times of crisis,” she said.

ECB Weapon

The ECB’s massive intervention earlier this month has let the decision-making paralysis among EU governments go unpunished. When sovereign bond yields spiked amid doubts by investors on whether indebted countries can afford the spending required to stem the fallout, the ECB announced a bond purchase program that brought down borrowing costs across the bloc.

But some leaders cautioned that not acting convincingly on the fiscal front could eventually undermine the ECB’s work. During the leaders’ discussion Greek Prime Minister Kyriakos Mitsotakis, who co-signed the letter calling for coronabonds, cautioned that if the bloc didn’t react, it could push the ECB toward an even larger program that would risk financial instability.

3/26/2020

The Two Economic Stages of Coronovirus


March 26 2020
By Christian Odendahl and John Springford 

European policy-makers must offset the huge costs of containing the virus, while keeping debt sustainable in all eurozone member-states. But they also need a plan to stimulate a V-shaped recovery.

Governments are deliberately curtailing economic activity for public health reasons. This is the first stage of the crisis, and in a CER analysis on March 10th, we explained how policy-makers must offset falling income for businesses and households. Most European governments have started to enact policies similar to our proposals: emergency lending to help firms with cashflow and banks with funding, short-time working policies and pay support to prevent unemployment. These policies will require enormous government deficits this year, and borrowing costs have risen in Italy, Spain, Portugal and Greece. But policy-makers must also plan for stage two of the crisis. They must prevent a weak recovery, by stimulating the economy as soon as the virus is sufficiently contained to allow people to return to work. What can governments do now to help the recovery? And what must the eurozone do now to ensure that all governments have the capacity to enact both stages of this plan?

Markets are unstable because investors do not know how long containment policies will last. And there is a risk that, once the crisis begins to ease, fiscal and monetary action is withdrawn too quickly, as happened after the financial crisis. Now, as then, governments are expanding deficits in order to keep businesses and households afloat. But from 2010, most governments embarked on austerity – and only few did so because of pressure from bond markets. Then the European Central Bank (ECB) raised interest rates in 2011.

Governments and central banks must be clear that they will stimulate the economy once the containment phase is lifted. This will make containment policies more effective now.

Governments and central banks must be clear that they will stimulate the economy once the strict containment phase is over. This will make containment policies more effective now. Knowing that stimulus is coming, banks will be more willing to lend, confident that future revenues will be higher than otherwise. Workers, especially the self-employed, will be more willing to stay at home to prevent transmission of the virus if they have increased confidence that there will be plenty of work once the emergency is over. And firms might even use the time they are temporarily closed to invest in their business.

Both monetary and fiscal policy are needed. The ECB should announce that it will tolerate a period of above-target inflation to compensate for the current undershoot: eurozone inflation has been hovering around 1 per cent for years. Last year, the ECB made clear that it wanted inflation to make a sustained recovery to 2 per cent before raising interest rates and stopping its bond purchase programme. It should now go further, and permit inflation to overshoot for two years to allow a boom to play out, without raising interest rates.

Fiscal policy should act on four fronts. Governments have provided loans to businesses to help them cope with falling revenues. But loans will raise debt burdens, which can curb investment. Governments should announce that part of these loans will be forgiven if the economy as a whole fails to make a strong recovery after the epidemic is contained. Companies should not be responsible for governments’ failure to overcome the virus and create the conditions for recovery. Governments should also legislate for generous tax relief for investment after the crisis through temporary tax credits.

The second front should be aid to the most affected services sectors. Here, the recovery will be weaker than in manufacturing: a cancelled restaurant visit, concert or holiday trip will rarely be rescheduled. To help raise demand, governments should announce today that these sectors will pay a lower VAT rate for a year, to boost consumption and activity (if prices are lowered in response) or repair balance sheets (if firms choose to use the tax cut to raise profits, and not lower prices). In 2009, the UK temporarily cut VAT, and the evidence suggests that 75 per cent of the cut was passed on to consumers.

The third front is consumption. Boosting consumer spending would help the most badly affected services sectors too. A one-time payment could be made as the pandemic eases, along the lines of the US’s 2008 ‘economic stimulus payments’ of around $300-600 per person. Research shows that consumers spent between 50 and 90 per cent of that money within three months of its disbursement. In countries like Germany that have a high tax burden on low incomes, permanent tax reductions on low incomes would be preferable, making work more attractive and expanding economic activity.

The final front is public investment. Many countries will have much higher public debt after the containment phase, and governments will be tempted to cut investment. Companies may anticipate that, and curb capacity now. If governments commit to a long-term programme of higher public investment after this crisis, firms dependent on public sector contracts will know that they can maintain – or even increase – capacity.

The eurozone’s fiscal hawks will argue, wrongly, that stimulus measures of this type make debt unsustainable. The ECB and the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), the eurozone’s bailout fund, have all the tools necessary to keep government borrowing costs down. On March 18th, the ECB announced €750 billion of new asset purchases, and, in a departure from usual practice, said they would be willing to buy more Italian assets, rather than buying from all countries in proportion to their ECB capital. This powerful commitment has eased tensions in markets.

European fiscal policy-makers should complement the ECB with collective action of their own. The ESM should help by providing bailout funds, with conditions to ensure spending is well-targeted on liquidity support to companies and wage support for workers. Ideally, this would be agreed for all eurozone member-states at once, rather than singling out Italy. A memorandum of understanding could make clear that the credit lines will only last for one year before having to be renewed. Policy-makers should also make clear that ESM funding will be increased if need be, through more joint borrowing by the member-states.

Of course, even well-designed stimulus programmes would raise public debt. But since they also increase economic activity, the crucial debt-to-GDP ratio may not increase much, or even fall. Monetary policy is currently weak because interest rates are near (or below) zero. In these conditions, deficit spending by governments tends to raise GDP faster than it raises public debt. This is particularly true if a pre-announced stimulus has positive economic effects during the epidemic, in reassuring businesses that revenues will be higher in the future, allowing them to pay for the loans taken on during the containment phase.

If Europe does not stand together, the consequences of the virus could be severe. Countries that fail to use fiscal policy to offset the deep recession will suffer permanent (and unnecessary) economic damage. In extremis, a renewed financial crisis in the eurozone would need to be contained, most likely through the ECB printing money and financing government deficits directly. Such a move is not as radical as it appears, since the economic hit from coronavirus will be severe but temporary, but it would almost certainly face fierce opposition in northern member-states. This virus is a very difficult test for the EU, but there is a broad expert consensus about the economics of the pandemic. And there will be no excuse if governments fail to act.

4/02/2018

How Europe’s Band-Aid ensures Greece’s bondage

http://jordantimes.com/opinion/yanis-varoufakis/how-europe%E2%80%99s-band-aid-ensures-greece%E2%80%99s-bondage

3/27/2018

Greece could create new market shocks as banks face critical test

https://www.cnbc.com/2018/03/26/greece-could-create-new-market-shocks-as-banks-face-critical-test.html

11/06/2015

The Greek Economy: Which Way Forward?


Πηγή: CERP
By Mark Weisbrot, David Rosnick, and Stephan Lefebvre
January 2015


Executive Summary

In the past six years the Greek economy has gone through a massive adjustment at a steep price, with unemployment currently at 25.8 percent and youth unemployment at 49.6 percent, and lost output of about 26 percent. The current account and primary government budget balances have been brought into surplus; Greece now has the largest cyclically adjusted primary budget surplus in Europe, at 6.0 percent of potential GDP.

The economy finally grew in 2014, by 0.6 percent, but the recovery is weak, slow and fragile. While some have attributed the nascent recovery to the success of years of austerity, in fact it is due to the near end of fiscal tightening. The cyclically adjusted budget surplus – which measures the government’s fiscal tightening -- moved from 5.7 percent in 2013 to 6.0 percent of GDP in 2014, or just 0.3 percentage points. In the three years prior, the adjustment had been 3.2 percent of GDP (2012-13), 3.8 percent of GDP (2011-12), and 5 percent of GDP (2010-11). It should be obvious that this huge drop-off in fiscal tightening would be the main cause of the return to growth.

The IMF projects unemployment to remain at 12.7 percent in 2019, yet this is considered “full employment,” since the economy will be above its potential GDP according to IMF estimates. In order to meet Greece’s current program debt targets, the government is required to run very large primary budget surpluses – more than 4 percent of GDP – for “many years to come,”beginning in 2016. This will be a serious drag on growth.

This paper argues that prolonged mass unemployment and reduced living standards, brought about by years of recession and budget cuts, are unnecessary, and that a robust recovery is feasible. It presents an alternative macroeconomic scenario with a moderate fiscal stimulus, which brings the economy much closer to full employment over the next five years, with a lower net debt than currently projected by the IMF. This alternative is just one of many possible scenarios, some ofwhich might include debt cancellation, or more help from the European Central Bank in maintaining low interest rates, especially in light of its recently announced quantitative easingprogram. The current program, which forecasts a weak recovery with many downside risks, as well as continued mass unemployment in the years ahead, should be replaced with policies that offer a much stronger and faster recovery.




The pitfalls of external dependence: Greece, 1829-2015



Πηγή: Brookings Institute
By Carmen M. Reinhart and Christoph Trebesch
5 Sept 2015

Abstract: Two centuries of Greek debt crises highlight the pitfalls of relying on external financing. Since its independence in 1829, the Greek government has defaulted four times on its external creditors, and it was bailed out in each crisis. We show that cycles of external crises and dependence are a perennial theme of Greek modern history – with repeating patterns: prior to the default, there is a period of heavy borrowing from foreign private creditors. As repayment difficulties arise, foreign governments step in, help to repay the private creditors, and demand budget cuts and adjustment programs as a condition for the official bailout loans. Political interference from abroad mounts and a prolonged episode of debt overhang and financial autarky follows. At present, there is considerable evidence to suggest that a substantial haircut on external debt is needed to restore the economic viability of the country. Even with that, a policy priority for Greece is to reorient, to the extent possible, towards domestic sources of funding.


11/05/2015

How did Greek banks perform under ECB stress test?



Πηγή: WEF
By Silvia Merler
3 Nov 2015

This article is published in collaboration with Bruegel. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

The ECB published the comprehensive assessment of the four major Greek banks (Alpha Bank, Eurobank, National Bank of Greece and Piraeus Bank) yesterday, in line with what was agreed in the third bailout programme for Greece. This exercise will form the basis for the recapitalisation operation foreseen as part of the programme, which will need to be carried out soon.

As was the case in 2014, the exercise comprises two parts: an asset quality review (AQR) and a forward-looking stress test.

The asset quality review is a point-in-time assessment of the accuracy of valuation of banks’ assets as of 30 June 2015, and provides a starting point for the stress test. The exercise yields an AQR-adjusted common equity tier 1 (CET1) ratio, to be compared to a threshold of 9.5% CET1 (which was also used as reference for the stress test).

The stress test provides a forward-looking view of the resilience of banks’ solvency to different levels of stress, taking the new AQR information into account. The stress test baseline scenario entailed a required minimum CET1 ratio of 9.5%, whereas the adverse scenario entailed a minimum CET1 ratio of 8%.

These requirements are quite different from those of the 2014 stress test, i.e. 8% baseline and 5.5% adverse. The ECB should explain this more clearly and explicitly. As a result, the exercise resulted in aggregate AQR-adjustments of €9.2 billion and overall, the assessment identified capital needs post AQR of €4.4 billion in the baseline scenario and €14.4 billion in the adverse scenario (table 1).




Source: ECB report

Piraeus bank has been the worst performer in the stress test, requiring 4.93 billion of new capital, followed by the National Bank of Greece (4.6 billion), Alpha Bank (2.7 billion) and Eurobank (2.1 billion). The impact of the AQR has been the largest on Piraeus, whereas Alpha Bank did not record any AQR-related shortfall.

The banks’ plan to plug the capital hole will need to be announced in the coming week, and both Piraeus and Alpha banks have started attempts to raise private capital already. Piraeus recently launched an exchange offer on 1.1 bn of subordinated and senior bonds, while Alpha bank announced a similar plan for a 1.1 bn bond swap last week. The additional capital needs that cannot be raised from private investors will reportedly be covered by the Hellenic Financial Stability Fund with a mix of new shares and cocos. The recapitalisation bill passed by the Greek government this week covers exactly these issues (see here for a summary of the main points).

Beyond the timing of the recapitalisation, which has been matter of discussion over the last weeks, a couple of things remain unclear. First, the biggest source of risk for the Greek banks may still be not accounted for. The exercise does not deal with Greek banks’ reliance on sizable Deferred Tax Assets (DTAs). For some banks, these make up about 50% of CET1 (as previously discussed). DTAs are by no means used by Greek banks only, and the issue is ultimately rooted in the definition of capital in our regulatory framework, so it would make absolutely no sense for the ECB to change the rule only for Greek banks in this exercise. Rather than solving the problem, this would delay finding a solution.


11/01/2015

Greek banks face $15.9b bill after economic debacle



Πηγή: AFRWeekend
1 Nov 2015

Greece's four main banks must raise €14.4 billion in fresh capital, the European Central Bank said, as investors and taxpayers face the cost of repairing the damage from six months of wrangling between the nation's government and its creditors.

An asset-quality review carried out by the ECB resulted in valuation adjustments of €9.2 billion for the National Bank of Greece SA, Piraeus Bank SA, Eurobank Ergasias SA and Alpha Bank AE, the Frankfurt-based supervisor said Saturday in a statement.

The banks' capital gap amounted to €14.4 billion under a simulated stress test scenario, and €4.4 billion under baseline macroeconomic assumptions. The four banks will have to submit recapitalization plans to the ECB's supervisory arm by November 6.

"Covering the shortfalls by raising capital would then result in the creation of prudential buffers in the four Greek banks, which will facilitate their capacity to address potential adverse macroeconomic shocks," the ECB said in the statement, adding that a minimum of €4.4 billion, corresponding to the AQR and baseline shortfall, is expected to be covered by private means.

The capital shortfall is "significantly lower than feared," German Deputy Finance Minister Jens Spahn said, while US undersecretary for international affairs Nathan Sheets said in an interview before the results that the health of the Greek financial system is now "clearly better" than a few months ago.

National Bank of Greece, the country's biggest bank by assets, has a total capital shortfall of €4.6 billion, including €1.6 billion from the baseline scenario.

Piraeus has the biggest shortfall of all the lenders, and needs to raise €2.2 billion under the baseline scenario, and €4.9 billion in total.

Piraeus reported on Saturday a net loss of €635 million in the first nine months of the year and an accelerating pace in the formation of sour loans.

Alpha Bank only needs to raise €263 million under the baseline scenario, out of a total shortfall of €2.7 billion.

Eurobank has the lowest aggregate shortfall, totaling €2.2 billion, with €339 million corresponding to the baseline scenario.

Attica Bank has a shortfall of €857 million in the baseline scenario and €1 billion in the adverse scenario, according to a separate comprehensive assessment conducted for the small lender by the Athens-based central bank.

"Alpha expectedly fared best and Piraeus expectedly fared worst," Paris Mantzavras, analyst at Athens-based Pantelakis Securities wrote in a note to clients after the publication of the results.

"Compared to our market estimates for the total capital bill, Eurobank is a positive surprise and National Bank a negative one."

The European Commission said in a statement that it is "encouraged" by the results, while Eurobank's Chief Executive Officer Fokion Karavias said that the lender's capital needs under the stress test's adverse scenario are "fully manageable."

Alpha Bank, in a filing to the stock exchange, said the result "demonstrates resilience," despite "higher hurdle rates and the repayment of €940 million of state preference shares in 2014, which further improved the quality of capital."

BAIL-OUT AGREEMENT

The government of Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras and Greece's European creditors reached a bail-out agreement this summer after months of wrangling that brought the country to the brink of leaving the currency union and resulted in capital controls.

Recapitalizing the country's lenders, after a month- long forced shutdown in July and record deposit bleeding, is the first step to restart the country's economy, which is still crippled by restrictions on transfers of capital and ATM withdrawals.

Lenders will ask their shareholders and bondholders to voluntarily offer to plug any holes identified by the ECB, before resorting to a €25 billion state backstop, according to a bank recapitalization bill which the Greek Parliament approved on Saturday. Taxpayers' funds will come from euro-area emergency loans under Greece's latest bailout agreement.

Common and preferred stock as well as other financing instruments, including unsecured senior liabilities, can be bailed in before a financial institution is eligible to use the public backstop of the state-owned recapitalization fund to cover its shortfall, according to the bill. Eurobank, Alpha Bank, and Piraeus have already extended swap offers to their bondholders, as they seek to reduce liabilities and boost their capital.

A spokesman for the European Stability Mechanism-- the currency union's crisis loans fund -- said that Greece can "quickly" use €10 billion,which have been mobilized for Greek bank recapitalizations and are currently sitting in a segregated account. With sufficient private-sector participation, the remaining €15 billion, which have been earmarked for capital injections under the terms of the bailout, will not be needed, the spokesman added, asking not to be named in line with policy.

This will also mean that Greece may not use the full €86 billion envisaged back in July.

"Capital shortfalls under the baseline scenario, which may be further reduced by the currently ongoing liability management exercises by the Greek banks and the restructuring plans to be submitted to the ECB, are manageable," analysts at Athens-based Euroxx Securities Vangelis Karanikas and Yiannis Sinapis wrote in a note to clients.

"All Greek banks should be able to cover the AQR and baseline needs through the private sector."

RECAPITALIZATION TERMS

The new recapitalization legislation empowers the state- owned Hellenic Financial Stability Fund to regularly evaluate the management and boards of Greek lenders that seek state aid.

Board members in Greek banks must have 10 years of international banking or finance experience, of which three years as board members.

At least one board member should have five years or more experience in bad loans management, and three independent board members, who will be presiding over all committees, mustn't have worked in a Greece-based bank during the past 10 years.

Officials who have served in senior political or public- sector posts over the past five years are banned from being appointed board members.

No bonuses will be distributed while a lender receives state aid and salaries of management are capped at the level of the annual compensation of the governor of the Bank of Greece, according to the legislation.

With assets totaling €296 billion at the end of June, the four banks tested by the ECB account for about 90 percent of the assets of credit institutions in Greece, the ECB said.

Attica Bank, which isn't considered a systemically significant lender, was assessed by the Bank of Greece, which identified a €1 billion shortfall.

The recapitalization bill which was approved Saturday allows HFSF to participate in capital raising actions of smaller banks and not just the four biggest ones.

"The shortfall number was in line with our expectation," Jonas Floriani, a London-based analyst with Keefe, Bruyette & Woods, said in an e-mail.

"The key now will be the capital plans and the recap framework."



7/08/2015

Milton Friedman, Irving Fisher, and Greece



Πηγή: New York Times
By Paul Krugman
July 7 2015


I continue to be amazed by how many people regard debt relief and devaluation as wild-eyed radical ideas; of course, it matters most that so many influential people in Europe share this ignorance. Anyway, for the record (and for my own future reference) I thought it would be helpful to post what Milton Friedman and Irving Fishe rhad to say about the Greek disaster. OK, they weren’t writing specifically about Greece — Friedman was writing in 1950, Fisher in 1933. But their analyses ring truer than ever.

First, Friedman (why oh why isn’t there a full electronic copy of this essay online?):



That tells you everything you need to know about why “internal devaluation” has been such a costly strategy — and why the ECB’s failure to move aggressively early on to achieve and if possible surpass its 2 percent inflation target was a major contributing factor to this disaster.

Then Fisher on why austerity hasn’t even helped on the debt:




The basic story of the European periphery — not just Greece — is one of a poisonous interaction between Friedman and Fisher, which has produced incredible suffering while failing to reduce the debt/GDP ratio, which even in star pupils like Ireland and Spain is far higher than when austerity began; the only success has been in suffering long enough so that some growth has finally resumed, and they can call it vindication.

The bizarreness of the whole thing is how flaky, speculative ideas like expansionary austerity became orthodoxy, while applying the economics of Fisher and Friedman became heterodoxy bordering on Chavismo.


2/19/2015

ECB risks crippling political damage if Greece forced to default

Anybody who thinks the loan package forced on Greece in 2010 was fair treatment should read the protests by every member of the IMF Board from the emerging market nations

Πηγή: The Telegraph
By Ambrose Evans-Pritchard
Feb 18 2015

The political detonating pin for Greek contagion in Europe is an obscure mechanism used by the eurozone's nexus of central banks to settle accounts.

If Greece is forced out of the euro in acrimonious circumstances - a 50/50 risk given the continued refusal of the creditor core to acknowledge their own guilt and strategic errors - the country will not only default on its EMU rescue packages, but also on its "Target2" liabilities to the European Central Bank.

In normal times, Target2 adjustments are routine and self-correcting. They occur automatically as money is shifted around the currency bloc. The US Federal Reserve has a similar internal system to square books across regions. They turn nuclear if monetary union breaks up.

The Target2 "debts" owed by Greece's central bank to the ECB jumped to €49bn in December as capital flight accelerated on fears of a Syriza victory. They may have reached €65bn or €70bn by now.

A Greek default - unavoidable in a Grexit scenario - would crystallize these losses. The German people would discover instantly that a large sum of money committed without their knowledge and without a vote in the Bundestag had vanished.

Events would confirm what citizens already suspect, that they have been lied to by their political class about the true implications of ECB support for southern Europe, and they would strongly suspect that Greece is not the end of it. This would happen at a time when the anti-euro party, Alternative fur Deutschland (AfD), is bursting on to the political scene, breaking into four regional assemblies, a sort of German UKIP nipping at the heels of Angela Merkel.

Hans-Werner Sinn, from Munich's IFO Institute, has become a cult figure in the German press with Gothic warnings that Target2 is a "secret bailout" for the debtor countries, leaving the Bundesbank and German taxpayers on the hook for staggering sums. Great efforts have made to discredit him. His vindication would be doubly powerful.

An identical debate is raging in Holland and Finland. Yet the figures for Germany dwarf the rest. The Target2 claims of the Bundesbank on the ECB system have jumped from €443bn in July to €515bn as of January 31. Most of this is due to capital outflows from Greek banks into German banks, either through direct transfers or indirectly through Switzerland, Cyprus and Britain.

Grexit would detonate the system. "The risks would suddenly become a reality and create a political storm in Germany," said Eric Dor, from the IESEG business school in Lille. "That is the moment when the Bundestag would start to question the whole project of the euro. The risks are huge," he said.

Mr Dor says a Greek default would reach €287bn if all forms of debt are included: Target2, ECB's holdings of Greek bonds, bilateral loans and loans from the bail-out fund (EFSF).

Markets remain relaxed. Yields on Portuguese, Italian and Spanish debt have been eerily calm. Investors are betting that the ECB could and would contain any fallout as its launches €60bn a month of quantitative easing, simply blanketing the bond markets of EMU crisis states.

This ignores the great unknown. Would the Bundestag or Holland's Tweede Kamer, or any creditor parliament, continue to let their national central banks supply unlimited Target2 credits to Latin bloc states via the ECB nexus once the system had blown up in Greece.



As a practical matter, the ECB itself would be in trouble. Any Target2 losses must be shared, according to the ECB's "capital key". The Bundesbank would take 27pc, the French 20pc, the Italians 18pc and so on, but these are uncharted waters.

"I do not believe that the Germans would allow the Bundesbank or the ECB to carry on with negative capital. They would demand recapitalisation and consider it a direct loss to the German state," said Mr Dor.

If so, Chancellor Merkel would face an ugly moment - avoided until now - of having to go to the Bundestag to request actual money to cover the damage. Other forms of spending would have to be cut to meet budget targets.

Syriza's leader, Alexis Tsipras, holds a stronger hand than supposed, and he is not shy in playing it. His speech to the Greek parliament on Tuesday night was flaming defiance. "We are not taking even one step back from our promises to the Greek people. We will not compromise, and we won't accept an ultimatum,” he said.

"There is a custom that newly-elected governments abandon their election promises. We intend to implement ours, for a change," he said, basking in approval from 82pc of Greek voters.

The new Greek plan to be submitted to Brussels is scarcely different from the proposals already rejected by the EMU finance ministers on Monday. The elemental demand is that there must be no further austerity. This has not changed.

The Eurogroup insists that the primary budget surplus be raised from 1.5pc of GDP in 2014, to 3pc this year and 4.5pc next year. As Nobel economist Paul Krugman says, they want to force a country that is already reeling from six years of depression - with the jobless rate still near 50pc - to triple its surplus for no other purpose than paying off foreign creditors for decades to come. They are doing to Greece what the Western allies did to a defeated Germany at Versailles in 1919: imposing unpayable and mutually-destructive reparations on a prostrate nation.

The fear of the Northern bloc is that austerity discipline will collapse across southern Europe if Greece wins concessions, but collapse is exactly what is needed for Europe to escape from a debt-deflation trap and prevent a second Lost Decade.


Alexis Tsipras

"It has become an ideological battle over austerity. Conservative governments want to ram though their retrenchment policies whatever the cost," says Sven Giegold, a German Green MEP.

Many of the attacks on Syriza are caricature. Athens is not taking on more public workers. It is rehiring 3,500 people "unjustly fired", offset by reductions elsewhere. "On privatisation, the government is utterly undogmatic," said finance minister Yanis Varoufakis.

"We are ready and willing to evaluate each project on its merits alone. Media reports that the Piraeus port privatisation was reversed could not be further from the truth," he told his Eurogroup peers. What Syriza will not do is carry out a "firesale" of assets at giveaway prices in a crushed market.

Talk of a debt write-off is a red herring. The Greeks are not asking for it. Mr Varoufakis wants a bond switch to "GDP-linkers" tied to future economic growth rates. He would probably settle for lower interest payments by stretching maturities.

The issue that matters is the primary surplus. Do the creditors wish to risk an EMU break-up and all that could follow in order to extract their last pound of flesh regardless of history's verdict?

Anybody who thinks the loan package forced on Greece in 2010 (with the collusion of the Greek elites) was fair treatment should read the protests by every member of the IMF Board from the emerging market nations. With slight variations, all said Greece needed debt relief from the outset, not fresh loans that stored greater problems. All said the bail-out was intended to save foreign banks and the euro itself at a time when there were no EMU defences against contagion, not to save Greece.

"The scale of the fiscal reduction without any monetary policy offset is unprecedented," said Arvind Virmani, India's former representative to the International Monetary Fund, according to leaked minutes. "It is a mammoth burden that the economy could hardly bear. Even if, arguably, the programme is successfully implemented, it could trigger a deflationary spiral of falling prices, falling employment and falling fiscal revenues that could eventually undermine the programme itself." This is exactly what happened.

Jean-Claude Juncker, the European Commission chief, implicitly recognises that Greece has a legitimate moral claim on Europe. He is quietly helping Syriza, just as France is quietly helping to shift the balance in the Eurogroup. The united front against Greece is a negotiating posture. It will fray under pressure.

Whether the EMU powers can resolve their own deep differences before Greece runs out cash - within a week, reports Ekathimerini - is an open question. Francesco Garzarelli, from Goldman Sachs, said he is "more worried" now than at any time since the start of the EMU crisis.


Jean-Claude Juncker

"The risk of a miscalculation in the negotiations remains high and will peak between now and month-end. Should Greece drop out of the single currency, the risk would become systemic. We doubt that even the major markets would be unaffected," he said.

On balance, and with little conviction, my view is that Chancellor Merkel will ultimately overrule the debt collectors and will yield in order to save Germany's 60-year investment in the diplomatic order of post-war Europe. It is a view shared by German eurosceptics such as Gunnar Beck, a legal theorist at London University.

"Germany's leaders can't let Greece leave the euro, and the Greeks know it. They will die in a ditch to defend the euro. This is our Eastern Front, our Battle of Kursk, and I'm afraid to say that it will end in unconditional surrender by Germany," he said.